Wednesday, February 25, 2015

73 Fundamental Free CFA Level 1 Practice Exam Questions on Economics

73 Fundamental Free CFA Level 1 Practice Exam Questions on Economics focus on fundamental economic concepts which you should know for your upcoming CFA exam. Through many multiple choice questions with instant answers, it’s pretty easy for you to understand all of the material presented here, consequently, successfully answer all of the given questions on economics. Reading through dry CFA material like CFA curriculum is something cumbersome for the economics topic. We would rather recommend you to study from our free CFA practice exam questions and answers and if possible practice daily as much as you can to solidify and revise all the knowledge before stepping into the important exam. Primary and 100% free, so it gives great comfort to many candidates, even for fresh test-takers. Test it now and share some comments with us!

To view full questions and answers, please kindly visit our site:  http://cfaexampreparation.com/541/73-fundamental-free-cfa-level-1-practice-exam-questions-economics/

In the case of savings, the same type of effects can apply. For example, say interest rates rise. Individuals may save more because the reward (price) for saving has risen, and individuals substitute future consumption for present consumption. However, higher interest rates also imply that less saving is required to attain a given future amount of money. If the latter effect (the income effect) dominates, then it is possible to observe higher interest rates resulting in less savings.
Given market prices and with a limited income. In effect, consumer choice theory first models what the consumer would like to consume, and then it examines what the consumer can consume with limited income.
That there is simply not enough of everything to satisfy the needs and desires of everyone at a given time.
Non-negative. Any given basket could have zero of one or more of those goods.
The good now becomes relatively less costly compared to other goods. That is, it becomes more of a bargain than other things the consumer could purchase; thus, more of this good gets substituted for other goods in the consumer's market basket. Additionally, though, with the decline in that price, the consumer's real income rises. That is the substitution effect and income effect of a change in the price of a good
completeness , One indifference curve
A good that increases in desirability with price. But they are not inferior goods and they do violate the axioms of choice that form the foundation of accepted demand theory.
the tangent to the indifference curve at any given bundle.
That the consumer can always make comparisons among all pairs of bundles of goods and identify preferences before knowing anything about the prices of those baskets.
The budget constraint outward along the horizontal axis but leaves the vertical intercept unchanged
His income and the prices he must pay for the goods he consumes.
At point a, where the highest indifference curve is attained while not violating the budget constraint.
That the pure substitution effect must always be in the direction of purchasing more when the price falls and purchasing less when the price rises. This is because of the diminishing marginal rate of substitution, or the convexity of the indifference curve.
The assumption of non-satiation (more is always better) ensures that all bundles lying directly above, directly to the right of, or both above and to the right (more wine and more bread) of point a must be preferred to bundle a.
Ordinal, as contrasted to a cardinal, ranking. Ordinal rankings are weaker measures than cardinal rankings because they do not allow the calculation and ranking of the differences between bundles.
The budget constraint becomes less steep
If Px were to rise, the budget constraint would become steeper, pivoting through the vertical intercept. Alternatively, if Py were to rise, the budget constraint would become less steep, pivoting downward through the horizontal intercept.
Qs are the quantities of each of the respective goods and services in the bundles. In the case of two goods—say, ounces of wine (W) and slices of bread (B)—a utility function might be simplyU = f(W,B) = WB or the product of the number of ounces of wine and the number of slices of bread.
The axiom of completeness
It rules out the possibility that she could just say, "I recognize that the two bundles are different, but in fact they are so different that I simply cannot compare them at all." The assumption of complete preferences cannot accommodate such a response.
different marginal rates of substitution when evaluated at identical bundles
transitivity , ever cross.
A fundamental model of how consumer preferences and tastes might be represented. It explores consumers' willingness to trade off between two goods (or two baskets of goods), both of which the consumer finds beneficial.
When comparing any three distinct bundles, A, B, and C, if A is preferred to B, and simultaneously B is preferred to C, then it must be true that A is preferred to C. It is assumed to hold for indifference as well as for strict preference.
All the combinations of two goods such that the consumer is entirely indifferent among them.
Consumer choice theory can be defined as the branch of microeconomics that relates consumer demand curves to consumer preferences.
Linear, constant
It is important to note that this equilibrium point represents the tangency between the highest indifference curve and the budget constraint. At a tangency point, the two curves have the same slope, meaning that the MRSxy must be equal to the price ratio, Px/Py.
A mathematical representation of the satisfaction derived from a consumption basket
If income were to rise, the entire budget constraint would shift outward, parallel to the original constraint,
From the indifference curve map and a set of budget constraints representing different prices of of the good
The MRSBW is the rate at which the consumer is willing to give up wine to obtain a small increment of bread, holding utility constant (i.e., movement along an indifference curve).
IP Q=−BQ
This assumption is sometimes referred to as the "more is better" assumption, that is, we usually assume that in at least one of the goods, the consumer could never have so much that she would refuse any more, even if it were free.
It is the assumption that the consumer knows his or her own tastes and preferences and tends to take rational actions that result in a more preferred consumption "bundle" over a less preferred bundle.
The company's production opportunity frontier shows the maximum number of units of one good it can produce, for any given number of the other good that it chooses to manufacture.

No comments:

Post a Comment